In the pursuit of suburban and regional renewal, have we fallen into the trap of thinking this is a responsibility for local governments? Have we become too reliant on local government powers to provide incentives to attract and stimulate development – things like density bonuses, rates relief, infrastructure charges relief – without lifting our thinking to wider opportunities to support targeted geographic areas? Are we relying on too few of the levers actually at our disposal?
Local government development incentives can be highly
effective, as Brisbane City Council showed when it targeted the limited supply
of 5 star hotel rooms across the city some years back, along with student
housing and seniors housing. Each sector was offered specific incentives
designed to bring forward proposals for adding to supply in that sector, in
support of city-wide economic development objectives. It worked, although it
wasn’t intended to support specific geographic areas within the city.
On a wider geographic level, these can become more problematic:
some local governments lack the resources to provide sufficient stimulus
options to make much difference to a project’s viability. And some location-specific
initiatives within one local government boundary might offer region-wide
benefits, but neighbouring local governments are unlikely to chip in out of a
sense of noblesse oblige. There are
many other valid reasons why the task of economic attraction shouldn’t be
delegated entirely to local governments.
Let’s take a hypothetical example of an outer suburban or
regional business district which has seen better days. Picture plenty of ‘For
lease’ and ‘For sale’ signs – some of the signs old enough to warrant a
heritage listing in their own right. Regional plans may identify it as a centre
of wider employment potential but without strategic policy support beyond the
reach of local government those sentiments are unlikely to be realised. Somehow
the ‘planning’ and the ‘doing’ never quite align. Our business district
continues to promise potential but nothing much changes.
If asked what’s needed to turn that around, I suspect many
of us would think the first order priorities are physical – infrastructure and
placemaking upgrades being top of the pops. These things are unquestionably
important in business attraction and centre renewal but, for the sake of
argument, what other levers could be applied? What other things could we do to
make a particular suburban or regional business district more appealing as a
place to base jobs?
For starters, we often overlook the impact of utilities
providers on the costs of both doing business and developing new assets. Many
years back, these were public utilities and some – such as water and sewerage –
were local government owned. Today many utilities providers work to a set of
objectives which do not include business attraction or incentivising development.
Nor do they respond to the economic development wishes of their former owners.
But their cost structures for new or upgraded infrastructure can add significantly
to local project costs and hence detract from the ability of getting our hypothetical
run-down centre up to speed. A new project in our renewal centre will be
competing with other existing centres where services are already in-ground, and
not as fully priced into the location costs; which puts us at an immediate cost
disadvantage. If we are serious about making outer suburban and regional
centres competitive, is it valid that we leave utilities off the team?
Another lever we usually don’t engage in incentivising regional
or suburban renewal is the tax lever. Payroll tax for example is levied at the
same rate whether you are major accounting or law firm in a CBD tower, or a mid-size
business in a suburban or regional location. Same payroll value, different
locations, same tax bill. (Payroll tax in Queensland kicks in at $1.3million
per annum in wages and is 4.75% for up to $6.5m per annum and 4.95% for over
$6.5m per annum. The Queensland Government introduced a regional discount in 2019 - of 1%. It's a start but unlikely to to be deal maker. It also doesn't apply to outer suburban or regional areas within South East Queensland). If our aim was to make our run down outer suburban centre or regional
centre more attractive to a cross section of businesses, is there any valid
reason we couldn’t offer payroll tax exemptions based on place of business? (Sure,
there’s a risk that some will set up “post box” locations to exploit
initiatives like this – there always are. But consider that the opportunity cost
of the lost revenue is relatively small if confined to specific locations, plus
the specific geographic location ought to make validity checks relatively easy?
This could actually be an easier tax measure to police than many already on the
statute books).
And if a “horses for courses” approach with payroll tax to favour
specific places of work is a potential lever, why not a similar approach to
things like land taxes, depreciation rates or the big one – income and company
taxes?
Let’s imagine our run down regional or outer suburban centre
given the collective support of Federal, State and Local Governments, along
with utility providers. Bring your business here and pay a concessional rate of
company tax, your workers will receive extra income tax rebates based on location,
your payroll taxes are zero, you are offered accelerated depreciation on built
assets and fixed equipment, land tax is half what you would pay elsewhere, while
energy, water and other utilities are less than what you’d pay in a major
centre. Plus the housing for your workers is plentiful and affordable. I’m writing
the economic development pitch already!
It’s only a crazy idea because we’ve never really been fair
dinkum about supporting the efforts of suburban or regional business districts
wanting to refresh their appeal. We have tended to assume that the inner cities
are where it’s at and directed the bulk of our infrastructure investment there
for that reason. We’ve also benchmarked and tuned our statewide and nationwide
tax and regulatory settings to the economic environments of major centres. Little
wonder that they have thrived while many suburban and regional centres have
struggled.
It isn’t enough to be able to offer cheap land as the prime location
incentive for regional or outer suburban areas – a tactic we often see resorted
to. It’s cheap for a reason, and land cost itself is rarely the deciding factor.
The cost of building in an outer suburban or regional area is either no
different or (often) more expensive than building in a major centre – so you
are effectively at a disadvantage from the outset. If the tax and regulatory framework
is also designed on a ‘one size fits all’ basis, whether you are regionally or
city based, then the odds start to become well and truly stacked against you.
We might stand a chance if we factored in the very high
costs of inner urban infrastructure needed to support a highly centralised
economy. For example, mass transit projects designed to ferry people to inner
city workplaces are eye-wateringly expensive, but those costs are borne by
taxpayers, usually without much dissent. Providing a similar ‘leg up’ to
regional or outer suburban centres, in the name of a more resilient and
dispersed economy that shares benefits more widely across the country, shouldn’t
prove as problematic as it seems.
Nothing in this is new of course. The notion of a ‘Northern
enterprise zone’ to develop the economy across the north of Australia gets a
regular airing, but rarely any traction. It’s an idea that has now been floated
so many times that it almost invites ridicule when it gets aired again. But
surely the idea can be no less ridiculous than the notion that the tax rates and
other government costs ought to be the same for businesses located in the CBDs
of major cities - where they are surrounded by taxpayer funded amenity - as it
is for outer suburban or regional business centres?
We need to begin to think more broadly about ways to support
a more geographically diversified economy. Continued concentration of our
economic fortunes into a handful of cities is a strategy fraught with risk, as
we are watching play out now in Melbourne thanks to Covid-19. Geographic
diversification is no longer an economic or planning pipe dream – it’s a matter
of national economic security.
No comments:
Post a Comment