As the year 2020 gets
underway, there will be the usual changes to various government fees, charges
and taxes. It’s nearly always up and public transport is no exception. This nearly
always leads to gripes that “public transport is too expensive” and that to “solve
congestion” we need more people to use public transport, so it should be
cheaper. Whether it’s expensive or cheap depends on who’s paying. The numbers
on this are interesting.
From January 7 in Queensland, public transport fares will
rise by the CPI – around 2%. A typical two zone trip will now cost $4.03 –
which is actually cheaper than in 2014 when the same trip would have cost
$5.96. A one zone trip will be $3.31 and a four zone (the furthest) will cost
$8.11 each way. Then there are various discounts for seniors, students and people
with various special needs. (And then of course there is substantial fare
evasion which, given fines are rarely enforced, means “free” travel for the
naughty ones).
None of this will mean much to 85% of you because only 15%
of us use public transport regularly. But almost 100% of us believe that more –
and cheaper – public transport is a key to solving congestion. Which we hope will
mean we can all get around more conveniently in our cars.
Few people however appreciate the extent to which every
single public transport trip is subsidised by the taxpayer. According to Translink’s
own reports: “the average fare trip paid by customers was $1.88 and the average
Queensland Government (ie Queensland taxpayer) subsidy was $7.12.” Their report notes that revenue from fares
makes up only 21% of funding.
So for every time the average fare paying passenger swipes a
nearly $2 fare off their Go Card, the taxpayer silently tips in over $7. Each
way. Per person. Per day.
“The… subsidy was based on network funding from the
Queensland Government (ie taxpayer) of $342.86 million less fare revenue of $90.57
million for the quarter” the report says. Which means (roughly) an annual
taxpayer subsidy of around $1.009 billion.
Many public transport advocates will argue that fare increases
are discriminatory in that they negatively impact lower income workers, and I
for one would be in hearty agreement with that sentiment, if only it were true.
Apart from the student and seniors concessions, the average public transport
user favours PT because they work in the inner city – which is where most
public transport routes head to, or come from. And for the average person, this
means they earn a substantially higher income than their suburban worker
counterparts, for whom PT is rarely a workable option.
Further, the average PT user does not commute from outlier
suburbs but a higher proportion get onboard within a roughly 5 or 10 kilometre
radius of the CBD. This also happens to correlate with higher average housing
prices. As noted in this
article in The Conversation: “the distribution of high-quality public
transport typically favours wealthier households within Australian cities.” You
can find loads more evidence about who actually uses PT and their demographic
and geographic characters on this excellent site: https://chartingtransport.com/)
Of course, if you are a lower income CBD worker using PT to
get to your inner city job, public transport could seem expensive. A two zone
trip - $4 each way – is $40 a week. On the median annual income of somewhere
around $60,000 per annum, that can mean a lot. But at the same time let’s keep
in mind that’s only 20% of what it costs – the taxpayer is funding that person’s
travel to the tune of around $140 per week.
Another argument often raised in the context of public
transport costs is the suggestion that we should bite the bullet and just make
it free (which means the taxpayer pays the lot). If my numbers are correct,
that would mean an additional $1.009 billion per annum (being the annual
taxpayer subsidy via Translink). There could be merit in this if it meant a
vastly higher usage of public transport leading in turn to much reduced
congestion and significant reductions in road and other network costs. The problem
with this would be if the PT network was suddenly overloaded, requiring vast
increases in capital investment to bring the network up to scale. And of course
vastly more people using PT would mean vastly more tax payer subsidies.
This is, however, unlikely in my view for the simple reason
that public transport only suits a finite proportion of the population.
Typically, it works for those with CBD or inner city jobs (only around 15% of
the regional population); those with regular clockwork-like hours (increasingly
few of us); those who do not have mixed journeys to work (for example no school
drop offs or pick ups); and so on. Making PT free could mean only a marginal
increase in patronage, but at a very substantial cost. The rest of us would be
cursing everyone else for not availing themselves of free public transport,
while we continue to stew in congested roads in our cars. I mean, it’s not our
fault – we need our cars. Not
everyone else does, do they?
(In Peter Seamer’s recent book ‘Breaking Point: The Future of Australian Cities’ he recounts the story of the decision to make Melbourne’s CBD trams “free.” All that happened is that the wealthy CBD workers took up the offer, crowding the trams to the point of overcrowding and leading to far fewer people actually walking. There was no net community gain).
So if you are among the nearly 15% of people who do make regular use of the public transport network, please don’t begrudge the taxpayer the fare increase and please don’t attack the politicians who have to announce it. Significant and overdue improvements are being made to public transport networks which users are not being asked to pay for. It’s a good deal and worth keeping in mind that for every dollar of the fare you are paying, the taxpayer is tipping in an extra four dollars. And they’re not complaining.
Two points:
ReplyDelete1. I presume the taxpayer subsidy numbers you use are for operational costs only? Are capital costs an additional subsidy? and
2. A good solution would be to fund the 'user' not the 'provider' of the service. In other words, if the actual cost of a journey is $10, then give the $10 to the user (passenger) and let the passenger make up his/her mind how to spend it. They may prefer to walk or buy a bike or ....
Good commentary Ross. Only thing I'd note that, though it is hard to disentangle the total costs involved, bus and ferry transportation in SEQ is notably less subsidised than rail. It's the very low patronage on QR services (in part due to poor service integration with buses, especially in Brisbane, as well as operational performance from that operator [I got short-shunted on a trip just yesterday]) that particularly distorts the overall subsidy per trip across all modes.
ReplyDeleteAgreed Matt and thank you. The main point I was hoping to register was simply that we often forget the hidden hand of the taxpayer in public transport costs. Your points about QR are spot on. And QR carries far fewer people than buses.
DeleteGood article, Ross. It's too easy for the punters to dismiss the costs and call for more subsidy. Remember, the (poor) services really support only a small number of users due to its CBD focus.
ReplyDeletea bathing ape
ReplyDeleteyeezy 500
supreme
golden goose shoes
kyrie shoes
nike sb
curry shoes
pg 4
yeezy
supreme hoodie
z8d91o6c22 m1f91h0f65 e0z72m1q56 o5v53o8q26 i3n04l1n05 i9k72b2v92
ReplyDelete